Wednesday, April 8, 2009

This is not a credit crisis - it is a debt crisis by Dirk Bezemer


Economic Viewpoint
This is not a credit crisis - it is a debt crisis*
Dirk J Bezemer

ABSTRACT

Using an analogy with ancient Babylonia as its leading motive, this Viewpoint argues that the credit crisis is a symptom of an underlying problem. Fuelled by government policies, unprecedented debt levels were run up in industrialized countries over the last quarter century. Present policies of financial sector bailouts maintain economic structures diametrically opposed to what Classical liberals such as JS Mill envisaged as a free market economy.

What Babylonians Knew

When he took office as leader of the most powerful nation on earth, his first act was to legislate a debt workout for the beleagured economy. Under his predecessors, the public financial system had produced a bad debt problem that now threatened to crush the economy. Many of his citizens had to pledge their incomes in debt servicing and financial fees. Others lost their homes and land as foreclosures were rampant. His people were looking to him for change and for relief.

No, this is not about Obama. The year was 1792 BC, the nation was ancient Babylonia and the leader was king Hammurabi. The workout was in fact a plain debt cancelation, or ‘Clean Slate’ - a social mechanism that allowed ancient civilizations to prevent their financial sectors from ruining the real economy and family livelihoods.

Recent archaeological finds of shubati clay tablets (ancient ledgers) indicate that Babylonia developed an extensive public financial sector. Its administrators had mastered the mathematics of exponentiation and applied compound interest rules. They used a precursor to modern double-entry bookkeeping and grasped its fundamental tenet that for every asset there is a liability, and for every credit a debit.

Their economic thinkers realized that financial sector expansion would bring exponential debt growth, inevitably beyond the economy’s ability to pay. Their system of financial regulation was for rulers to periodically declare a Clean Slate. This applied to debt denominated in barley (the household staple)which families owed to the temple-state public financial system. Households had typically run up such debts as liabilities for crop-sharing rents and water fees. In contrast, commercial debts held by traders and denominated in silver were not forgiven.

Ancient Babylonians recognized the difference between the consequences of commercial risk taking which traders could carry, and the consequences of financial liabilities created by public sector policy, which threatened households’ livelihoods (see Wray, 2002; Hudson & Van de Mieroop, 2002; Hudson &Wunsch, 2004).

You could be forgiven for mistaking the US (or the UK, for that matter) for a debt-ridden Babylonia on the eve of a Clean Slate. Though 3,801 years apart, the similarities are striking.

But at least the Babylonians had learnt how to deal with debt before it crushed them. At the moment, we haven’t. It is the elephant in the room that no one talks about.

Credit Boom, Debt Growth

From the mid-1980s, most industrialized economies implemented financial policies that stimulated a credit boom without debt management provisions. As any Babylonian economist could have predicted, the debt overhead imposed on their real sectors has since grown unchecked and exponentially.

Stimulated by public policies of generous credit facilities and artificially low interest rates, banks moved away from their traditional role of deposit takers and credit providers to households and business, and engaged in merchant banking and securities trading. In creating and trading in financial innovations such as the now-infamous credit default swaps and similar instruments, they created serial bubbles in dotcom stocks, real estate, and currency trade.

All this happened not only with the tacit approval of government, but with its active support via monetary policy. Now that the grapes turn sour, this support continues in the form of bank bailouts at the costs of real sector employment, profit, jobs and even homes - a perversion of the Clean Slate philosophy. Our real problem is not that credit flows have dried up. It is that we have not even started to recognise what was central to Babylonian financial management.

Debt is the problem, lack of credit is a symptom. The size of the debt had grown out of control well before the credit crisis broke. Total liabilities from the US real economy to its financial sector amounted to only 1.5 times its GDP in 1980, but the multiple rose to 2 (1985), 3 (1996), 4 (2003) and then 4.7 (2007) 3 (BEA, 2009).

Growing ‘investment’ in financial assets came at the price of diverting finance from investment in US manufacturing structures from 5.5% of its GDP in the 1970s, down to 4% (1980s), 3% (1990s) and then below 2% (2000s). It also diminished demand for real output as US households in 2007 paid over a fifth of their after-tax, disposable income to the financial sector in debt servicing and financial fees. The US had become an economy trying to drive with the brakes on.

Self-propelled debt growth can be understood in terms of externality effects described in modern microeconomic models, where one agent’s actions change the costs and benefits of others’ choices. As prices are set at the margin, trade in a fraction 1/n of the market at a price increment p sends up total market valuation (and thereby collateral values) by np, so stimulating more lending in the entire market.

Other externalities operated through herding behaviour and falling costs of credit during the recent boom. And with compound interest, each loan requires additional debt creation for loan servicing. So in a number of ways, loans beget loans and without regulation, debt growth is self-propelled. With active government encouragement, it is a swelling tide. We tried to ride that wave for two decades, but it is now time to build a dike. The flood is such that no one will keep dry feet. But at least the real economy of households and businesses should be saved from drowning. In line with sound free market principles, those who build up the risks must now bear the brunt.

The current debt burden was obscured for a time by the illusion of wealth during the long asset price boom-turned-bubble of the last quarter century. Thanks to rising prices of real estate and its derivative instruments, US households’ ‘net worth’ increased from 4.7 times disposable household income in the 1980s and 1990s to a multiple of 5.9 in 2000 and 6.1 in 2007. The inevitable end to the asset price rally came with the turnaround in the US real estate market in the summer of 2006. Sudden net negative equity impaired households’ ability to keep borrowing against asset values to keep paying for a growing debt. Bank lending came to a standstill, but not debt repayment.

The Misplaced Sanctity of Debt

And yet it is unwise to try and pay off this debt, and so to favour banks as creditors over households and firms, their debtors. This policy relies on the image of banks as passively supplying loans demanded by the public, who must therefore now face the consequences of its choices.

This image stands in stark contrast to reality. The debt was run up recklessly in a lending spree where commercial banks and Central Banks (foremost, the Federal Reserve and the Bank of England) worked together to keep credit flowing. There is no moral imperative for debtors in the real economy to shoulder the bulk of the costs now that the boom has turned into crisis. Neither is that feasible. The debt represents a burden far beyond what the real economy can pay off, even if it keeps trying (as it now does) for decades to come. The current attempt is futile and harmful. It drains resources away from real demand and investment and absorbs any government package intended to stimulate the real economy. This is worse than driving with the brakes on - it is like trying to start up with the brakes on. It cannot be done.

What is true for the US is true for the global economic system. Outstanding derivatives have reportedly reached USD 1.14 quadrillion worldwide (BIS 2009). But policymakers do not seem to realize what was plain to your proverbial Babylonian economist. The credit crisis is the symptom, the debt is the cause. Without a debt workout, recovery is beyond the horizon no matter how many bank bailouts. Present policies of financial sector support are the inverse of a Clean Slate – they artificially maintain debt claims by keeping so many creditors in business to pursue their debtors. For all our economic sophistication, ancient Babylonians would be stunned by our lack of perception.

Classical Liberalism’s View of Rentier Incomes

Rescheduling the debt (which will be inevitable anyway) will one way or another hurt those living on debt servicing income - banks and financial institutions. Today’s economists shy away from this as they are trained to think of the financial sector in toto as indispensable to the real economy. Classical liberalism had a very different view. Its vision of a free market included freedom from the burden of rentier income (as, for instance, enjoyed by land owners).

Liberalism’s intellectual giant John Stuart Mill made an important distinction between capital used productively and capital kept idle by government taxation and by rentier claims. Payment for such privileged asset ownership, Mill (1848) wrote, “is not one of the expenses of production; and the necessity of making the payment out of capital makes it requisite that there should be a greater capital ... than is naturally necessary, or than is needed …in a different system. This extra capital, though intended by its owners for production, is in reality employed unproductively.”

Banks today operate under a state-given privilege to create and trade financial assets. If managed well, these assets help the real economy to save, to invest, to smooth consumption and to diversify risk. But just like the landed gentry in Mill’s days, the financial sector has the power to inflate asset prices, reaping windfall gains which simultaneously raise the costs of production to the real economy, smothering its progress.

When this dynamic is set in motion, the financial sector expands and the real sector (where most jobs and profit are generated) stagnates, as has happened in the US and UK since the 1980s. This is the conflict of interest that public policy must address. But monetary policy and the public debate have neglected this dimension since the 1980s. The constructive role of finance in economic growth was widely publicized during the credit boom in textbook lore, academic research and business journalism. Its potential for draining the real economy of liquidity - the lifeblood of economic transacting - in a boom-gone-bust has only recently become painfully clear.

But it is age old. Mill (1844) already warned that “the inclination to borrow has no fixed or necessary limit”… and that a banker responding to this by ”issuing paper which is inconvertible, levies a tax on every person who has money in his hands or due to him. He so appropriates to himself a portion of the capital of other people, and a portion of their revenue.”

Mill the moral philosopher is also clear that he considers this an “iniquity”. His problem with taxes was that it ”… limits unnecessarily the industry of the country: a portion of the fund destined by its owners for production being diverted from its purpose, and kept in a constant state of advance…" (Mill, 1848).

Today, a fifth of the disposable income that Americans could spent in support of the productive economy is kept “in a constant state of advance” to the financial sector, with active government support. This implicit tax is the iniquity to be redressed.

A Bankrupt Merchant Bank is not the End of the World

The drain of liquidity from the real economy to the financial sector must be decreased for a recovery to start. The important point is that it is, in Mill’s words, not “naturally necessary”. We can do without much of those financial claims, and the firms that live off them. Really, we can.
This comes as a shock to economists, policy makers and the public who have been told for decades that the financial sector is to be nurtured, and now to be saved.

But this view ignored the productive and unproductive roles that the financial sector can play, a distinction central to classical liberal economics and social policy. Slimming in the financial sector would improve rather than impair its ability to serve the real economy. Not all that long ago, the US economy did well with a financial sector only a third of its present size. Do we really need all of the other two thirds today, claims and all?

So let market forces work to effect a solution to the debt problem that underlies the credit crisis. This, after all, is what bankruptcy is for. It is a legally acknowledged and orderly debt workout mechanism and the natural consequence of commercial overexposure.

A shrinking of the financial sector - its most speculative part, preferably – by allowing bankruptcies would proportionally force it to relinquish its stifling debt claim on the real economy. As soon as a debt workout is put in place, recovery can start - but not earlier. Learn from Babylonia.

Dr Dirk J Bezemer is a Fellow at the Research School of the Economic and Business Department, University of Groningen in the Netherlands. His research is in comparative economic systems. Contact: d.j.bezemer@rug.nl

* I thank Michael Hudson for helpful comments on an earlier version of this paper and Arno Daastoel for help with locating data.

BEA (2009) Data from the Bureau of Economic Analysis at http://www.bea.gov. Accessed
March 2009

BIS (2009) Data from the Bank for International Settlements at http://www.bis.org.
Accessed Marc h 2009

Hudson, M and M vd Mieroop, eds. (2002) Debt and Economic Renewal in the Ancient Near East. Baltimore: CDL Press

Hudson, M and C Wunsch, eds. (2004) Creating Economic Order: Record-Keeping,
Standardizations, and the Development of Accounting in the Ancient Near East. Baltimore:CDL Press

Mill, JS (1844), Essays On Some Unsettled Questions of Political Economy, Essay IV: OnProfits, and Interest. At http://www.econlib.org/library/Mill/mlUQP.html

Mill, JS (1848), The Principles Of Political Economy: With Some Of Their Applications
To Social Philosophy, Book I, Chapter 4: Of Capital. At http://www.econlib.org/library/Mill/mlP4.html#Bk.I,Ch.IV

Wray (2004) (ed.) Credit and Sate Theories of Money: the Contributions of Michael Innes
Cheltenham UK: Edward Elgar

SOURCE: Gang of 8

No comments: